Overview of the problem
Are there different patterns of technological innovation across the climate zones of the globe? The economic literature shows that technological innovation is driven by several concomitant forces in specific geo-economic places (Coccia, 2005a, 2007, 2009a, 2010a, 2010b, 2010c, 2010d, 2012b, 2012c, 2012d, 2012e, 2014a, 2014b, 2014c, 2014e; Feldman and Kogler, 2010; Hall and Rosenberg, 2010; Coccia et al., 2012; Coccia and Wang, 2015). Geographical characteristics of certain areas support concentration and location of innovative activities and are vital determinants of new technology (Krugman, 1991). The new geography of innovation analyses several factors relating to the origin and diffusion of technological innovation, such as spatial proximity and agglomeration (Rosenberg, 1992; Smithers and Blay-Palmer, 2001; Howells and Bessant, 2012). However, little is known about the relationship between climate and technological performance. In general, climate is the main geographical factor that affects human activity and economic development (Chhetri et al., 2010, 2012). Climate and the environment also play a vital role in spurring and diffusing technological innovation, though this is a difficult assumption to test (Ruttan, 1997; Abler et al., 2000; Moseley et al., 2014; Robbins et al., 2014; see also Feldman and Florida, 1994). This study endeavours to explain how climate causes and sustains innovative outputs in specific areas. It also explores the association between technological performance and latitude.
The backdrop of prior research
The new economic geography argues that ‘all production depends on and is grounded in the natural environment’ (Hudson, 2001, p.300). A vital element of the natural environment is the climate system, based on the atmosphere, hydrosphere, cryosphere, lithosphere and biosphere. In general, the climate of a place is affected by its latitude, altitude, land, water system, etc. The climate affects natural resources, the natural environment and human activities. Long ago, Montesquieu (1947 [1748]) argued that the climate shapes human attitude, culture and knowledge in society.
Feldman and Kogler (2010) argue that the natural advantages of resource endowments and climate in certain places induce innovation and economic growth (Hayami and Ruttan, 1985; Ayres, 1998; Coccia, 2009b, 2009c; Coe et al., 2012; Moseley et al., 2014; Robbins et al., 2014). Others focus on the relationship between natural resources and the development of new technology (Ruttan, 1997; Gitay et al., 2001; Rodima-Taylor et al., 2012). In particular, they argue that the complex societies of temperate latitudes require inputs for their production processes, which are derived from the natural environment and climate as resources (Turner et al., 1994). This effective demand for natural resources spurs technological innovation, by a process of learning and adaptation, which improves the use of resources to support the socio-economic development of specific areas (Dicken, 2003). Ruttan (1997) argues that the development and adoption of new technology are attributable to changes in the geographic, economic and social environment (see Goldberg, 1996). Hayami and Ruttan (1985) explain the sources of technological change with the hypothesis of induced innovation: the process by which societies develop technologies that facilitate the substitution of relatively abundant (hence, cheap) factors of production for relatively scarce (hence, expensive) factors/resources. Lichtenberg (1960) shows that geographical factors, rather than proximity to raw materials or markets, influence the production of knowledge and the cumulative nature of several innovations (see also Macdonald, 1989; Krugman, 1991; Agee and Crocher, 1998; Lamberton, 1998; Coccia, 1999, 2004; Feldman and Audretsch, 1999; Cariola and Coccia, 2002; Audretsch and Feldman, 2003; Crevoisier, 2004; Coe et al., 2012; Howells and Bessant, 2012). At a later stage, knowledge spillover and skilled labour support further technological change (Feldman, 2003). In effect, a favourable climate also induces a better ‘institutional thickness’ (Amin and Thrift, 1993), which provides a platform for organizing people and resources in order to support knowledge creation and innovative outputs (Allen, 1997; Marceau, 2000; Rosenthal and Strange, 2003).
The main examples of these fruitful relations are to be found in specific places in temperate latitudes, such as Italy during the Rinascimento, England during the Industrial Revolution and the United States in the nineteenth century. Innovation is associated with a range of forces and circumstances, such as the resurgence of societies after conflict (Coccia, 2015), demographic change (Coccia, 2014a), high democratization (Coccia, 2010b), appropriate economic governance, secure property rights, predominant religions and efficient institutions (Coccia, 2009a, 2014b). Audretsch and Feldman (1996) confirm that the agglomeration of innovative activities and firms is related to advantages in the natural environment, available resources and other factors of physical geography. In general, this concentration of human and geo-economic resources is located in specific geographical places, such as major cities, long known to be society’s predominant engines of innovation and growth (Bettencourt et al., 2007). However, the literature of the geography of innovation is yet to explain the relationship between the human activity of technological innovation and climate zones. The next section presents a methodology to analyse this association.
Methods
The study design is based on the following hypothesis:
The present study ascertains whether empirical evidence substantiates this hypothesis. The causal model of the study is schematically summarized in Figure 1.
Causal model of the nexus between temperate climate and technological and economic progress in society
The sample is derived from 109 countries (see Appendix A). The indicators of the statistical analysis and sources of data are shown in Table 1. In particular, innovative outputs are measured by the patents of residents, which indicate the current innovation of countries and commercially-promising inventions (Coccia, 2010a, 2012b).1 Hunt and Gauthier-Loiselle (2010, p.32) claim that ‘the purpose of studying patents is to gain insight into technological progress, a driver of productivity growth, and ultimately economic growth’. Patents have a positive influence on patterns of technological innovation and are the most common metrics of innovative output used to analyse technological performance in modern countries (see Jaffe and Trajtenberg, 2002; Coccia, 2010a, 2012b). The paper also considers other metrics of innovative outputs in order to increase the robustness of the empirical analysis:
- •
Research and Development (R&D) expenditures (as % of GDP)
- •
number of researchers in R&D
- •
number of scientific and technical journal papers.
These indicators reveal, approximately, the national level of technological innovation, which is the most important component of technological change (Coccia, 2010a, 2012a).
In addition, geographic and demographic variables are used to detect the barycentre of innovation across countries (Coccia, 2014a). The statistical analysis considers climate zones based on the world map of the Köppen–Geiger climate classification (see Kottek et al., 2006). This classification is critical to understanding different patterns of technological innovation (Zscheischler et al., 2012). The study divides the world into temperate and non-temperate climate zones (equatorial, arid and polar climates). Countries are located in these specific climate zones by latitude. Data were subjected to horizontal and vertical cleaning, excluding some years with missing values and/or outliers. The normal distribution of variables is checked by Kurtosis and Skewness coefficients, as well as by the normal Q–Q plot. As some variables do not have normal distributions, a logarithmic transformation has adjusted these distributions in order to apply correctly descriptive statistics, correlation analyses, ANOVA (Analysis of Variance) and parametric estimates. Time lags between variables are considered in order to analyse logical linkages better. Data are from the database of the World Bank (2008).
A preliminary statistical analysis is performed by descriptive statistics and bivariate correlation for temperate and non-temperate climates. The main statistical analysis is based on ANOVA, which considers two climate zones: temperate and non-temperate. In some statistical analyses, this study uses three climate zones: non-temperate climate, North temperate climate and South temperate climate. The statistical hypotheses of the ANOVA are:
H0: average level of technological outputs in temperate latitudes = average level of technological outputs in non-temperate latitudes
H1: average level of technological outputs in temperate latitudes ≠ average level of technological outputs in non-temperate latitudes
The expectation was that the ANOVA would reject H0 in favour of H1 (i.e. the average level of innovative outputs – measured by patents – in temperate latitudes is higher than in countries located in non-temperate latitudes). The robustness of results is checked by the Levene test of variance homogeneity, Test T of equality of mean, and the Welch–Brown–Forsythe test of robustness for equality of mean.
In order to determine the geo-economic area that is favourable/adverse to technological outputs (by using geographical coordinates), this study applies the following working equations:
LN patent applications per million people = f (longitude)
LN patent applications per million people = f (latitude)
The specification is based on cubic models since they fit very well with data scatter (Appendix B). The models (B1) and (B2) in Appendix B are estimated by the ordinary least squares method. The estimated relationships are polynomial functions, continuous and infinitely differentiable. The classic mathematical optimization method applied to these estimated relationships provides the local optimum/minimum that indicates the favourable/adverse geographical zone for supporting/impeding technological innovation.2
This study has also selected the largest 10 cities in each of 109 countries from a geographical database (GeoNames, 2014). These cities are associated with geographical coordinates (longitude and latitude) in order to compute the innovative centre of gravity of the country: in particular, the arithmetic mean of its geographical coordinates (longitude x i and latitude y i ) weighted by its population n i (see Appendix B, Eq. B3). The centre of gravity of innovative outputs also takes into account the roundness of the earth for extensive countries (Appendix B, Eqs. B4-B5). In fact, the geographical barycentre of the country, based on larger cities, is the predominant engine of innovation and wealth creation (Dicken, 2003, pp.69–76), confirming the benefits of urbanization economies that support innovation by means of the accumulation of human and physical capital (c.f. also Coccia, 2001; Coccia and Rolfo, 2007, 2009; Coccia and Cadario, 2014). Larger cities encourage the emergence and growth of a variety of infrastructural, economic, social and cultural facilities, and as a consequence, technological innovation (Bettencourt et al., 2007). This study also analyses the spatial variability of innovative outputs by applying the decomposition of territorial dispersion and the decomposition of normal deviation in temperate and non-temperate climates (Statistical equations in Appendix B, Eqs. 6B-7B).
Empirical support for hypothesis ϕ
Figure 2 shows that indicators of technological innovation, demography and economic performance have an arithmetic mean in temperate climate zones that is higher than that in non-temperate climate zones (for details, see Table C1 in Appendix C). Bivariate correlation (Pearson’s r) displays strong positive association between patent applications of residents (innovative outputs) and GDP per capita; human development index; and population in urban agglomerations >1 million (% of total population) in both temperate and non-temperate climates (except the correlation between PAR and PUA in temperate climates, where Pearson’s r is lower: 0.207; see Table C2 in Appendix C). ANOVA and test of comparison of the arithmetic mean of innovative outputs between temperate and non-temperate climates confirm the results (Appendix C, Table C3): the average LN patent 1995–2001 per million people of countries in temperate climates is much greater than in countries in non-temperate climates, thereby supporting the alternative hypothesis H1 (i.e. temperate climate is positively associated with technological output).

Arithmetic mean of innovative, economic and demographic indicators between non-temperate and temperate climates
Figure 3 confirms that the arithmetic mean in North and South temperate climate zones is higher than in non-temperate climate zones. The Levene test and test of robustness for equality of mean (Welch–Brown–Forsythe) further confirm the positive effects of temperate latitudes on innovative outputs: the average LN patent 1995–2001 per million people of countries in North and South temperate climates is much greater than in countries located in non-temperate climates (see Tables C3–C5 in Appendix C). The application of other indicators of innovative outputs confirms these results. In order to determine the geographical centre of gravity that optimally supports technological outputs (PAR = patent applications of residents 1995–2001), the maximum/minimum of the estimated relationships of geographic coordinates is calculated (see Table C6 in Appendix C and Appendix D). The latitude and longitude favourable (or adverse) to innovative outputs are in Table 2.
Geographical coordinates | Max patent applications of residents (1995–2001)*Area favourable to innovative output | Min patent applications of residents (1995–2001) Area adverse to innovative output |
---|---|---|
Longitude | 90° 52’ | -24° 12’ |
Latitude | 60° 59’ | -4° 19’ |
Note:
Indicates maximum value. According to the sexagesimal system of angular measurement, °=grade=1/360 circle; ′ = primes = 1/60 grade.
The geographical barycentre of the globe that maximizes innovative outputs is at longitude 90° 52′ and latitude 60° 59′. These geographical coordinates are in the northern hemisphere in temperate latitudes (in the Russian Federation to the north-east of Novosibirsk). This result shows that innovative outputs are greater in temperate climate zones of the hemisphere. The geographical barycentre that minimizes innovative outputs is at longitude –24° 12′ and latitude –4° 19′ (below the equator, on the east coast of Brazil). This result confirms that high innovative outputs are lower in the non-temperate parts of the globe. Table 3 also shows that innovative outputs (first column) are in temperate climate zones with low territorial dispersion (last column).
Variable: LN patent applications of residents(1995–2001) | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Climate zones | Average LN patent applications of residents (standard deviation) | Geographical barycentre | Territorial dispersion
![]() | |
Average longitude | Average latitude | |||
Temperate latitudes | 4.06 (1.99) | 28° 28′ | 41° 25′ | 56° 22′ |
Non-temperate latitudes | 0.22 (1.81) | -53° 2′ | 14° 25′ | 127° 53′ |
Total | 3.18 (2.53) | 27° 10′ | 40° 59′ | 59° 12′ |
Note:
According to the sexagesimal system of angular measurement, °=grade=1/360 circle; ′ = primes=1/60 grade.
Decomposition of the territorial dispersion of patent applications of residents (PAR) shows that the territorial dispersion of innovative outputs is mainly within groups (Table 4, a). However, the divergence of the barycentre between non-temperate and temperate climate zones plays a vital role in explaining the average difference between innovative outputs. In particular, the normal decomposition of total deviation (Table 4, b) shows that an important source of variability of innovative outputs is also between groups of temperate and non-temperate climate zones (40.62%). Hence, technological outputs are affected by climate and positively influenced by temperate latitudes. This result further substantiates the HPϕ and nexus in model of Figure 1.
(a) Decomposition of territorial deviation | Temperate | Non-temperate | Temperate vs. Non-temperate | |
Value | 5,737,078= | (5,117,452.52+ | 429,209.03)+ | 190,416.34 |
100%= | (89.20%+ | 7.48%)+ | 3.32% | |
Dev(X, Y)= | Within + | Between | ||
(b) Decomposition of total deviation | Temperate | Non-temperate | Temperate vs. Non-temperate | |
Value* | 3,292.69= | (1,571.13+ | 383.97)+ | 1,337.59 |
100%= | (47.72%+ | 11.66%)+ | 40.62% | |
Dev(X, Y)= | Within + | Between | ||
Arithmetic* mean | 3.18 Total | 4.06 Temperate climate | 0.22 Temperate climate | – |
Standard deviation* | 2.53 Total | 1.99 Non-temperate climate | 1.81 Non-temperate climate | – |
Note:
Logarithmic value.
The statistical analysis shows, ceteris paribus, that, on average, innovative outputs are associated with temperate latitudes and with favourable factors of physical and human geography. In short, technological innovation, as a crucial human activity, thrives in temperate latitudes. This result also explains, on average, the localization of the majority of high-income countries in a temperate climate. In contrast, low- and middle-income countries are, on average, in non-temperate latitudes (Coccia, 2008, 2010e, 2014d). Adverse natural environment for human activities in non-temperate climate zones has negatively affected the creation of institutions, economic governance and democratization over time. These disadvantages induce low investment in physical and human capital, as well as low economic efficiency in the use of these factors to support technological innovation and achieve higher income (North, 1981). However, Acemoglu et al. (2001) argue that ‘Once the effect of institutions is controlled for, countries in Africa or those closer to the equator do not have lower incomes’.
In addition, within temperate and non-temperate climate zones there is high variability in innovative performances because the relationship between climate and technological outputs is also affected by other socio-institutional and cultural factors (Coccia, 2005b, 2005c, 2011, 2012a, 2014a). For instance, Spain and the UK are in the same climate zone, but Spain has an annual average of about 57 patents per million people, whereas the UK has an annual average of roughly 334 patents (Coccia, 2014a). Institutions, democratization, cultural factors and other socio-economic factors differ across countries and tend to generate, ceteris paribus, a great variety of economic and technological performance, although the countries are in similar climate zones. In brief, climate is an important determinant in explaining differences in income per capita and innovative outputs across countries. However, there are also other complex factors that affect patterns of technological innovation in similar latitudes, such as national systems of innovation, demographic change, predominant religion, democratization, institutions, secure property rights and efficient economic governance (Coccia, 2014a, 2014b, 2015).
Explanation of the nexus between temperate climate and innovative outputs
In general, the statistical evidence seems to support hypothesis ϕ: on average, high innovation outputs are explained by the localization of countries in temperate climate zones. This result is attributable to some fruitful linkages: climate influences the natural environment, resources and human activities. In particular, temperate latitudes, with appropriate geographical factors, have attracted humans who created complex societies. These societies, by a process of learning and adaptation, use the natural resources of the environment as inputs to the production processes. The effective demand for natural resources generated stone (lithic) technology for better use of natural resources. Subsequently, concentration of human resources and capital created dense social networks and trusting environments to support further socio-economic development, patterns of technological innovation and their path-dependency (Coccia, 2009b, 2013; Lee and Rodríguez-Pose, 2013). Ethnologists, such as Tylor and Morgan, view: ‘the production of novelties – new ideas, new ways of doing things, and the like – as the underlying force that propels cultures up the ladder of cultural complexity’ (quoted by O’Brien and Shennan, 2010, p.4). In effect, concentration of people and social interactions in temperate latitudes support an effective circulation and diffusion of information, facilitating discoveries, inventions and innovations by new combinations of ideas and technical knowledge: ‘Population growth produces an absolutely larger number of geniuses, talented men, and generally gifted contributors to new knowledge whose native ability would be permitted to mature to effective levels when they join the labour force’ (Kuznets, 1960, p.328).
In addition, concentration of people in temperate latitudes leads to greater demand for new goods and services and, as a consequence, to demand-driven innovation. These crucial linkages generate an impetus for technological progress and economic growth in specific places in these tepid latitudes (Coe et al., 2012). Hence, innovative activity in the specific socio-economic context of temperate climate is a combination of tangible and intangible elements that supports patterns of technological innovation (innovative milieu). Temperate latitudes have fruitful geographical factors that support some natural advantages for human activities and are a major source of attraction for populations. This natural and socio-economic environment induces the transmission of knowledge by intensive contacts among people (e.g. face-to-face interactions), and the sharing of common attitudes/interests (Von Hippel, 1994; Allen, 1997; Marceau, 2000; Feldman and Romanelli, 2006; Cavallo et al., 2014a, 2014b). Kremer (1993, pp.684–85) notices that: ‘among technologically separate societies, those with high population had faster growth rates of technology and population’. Moreover,
When people with common technical interests concentrate geographically, dense local social and professional networks emerge as their close proximity leads them to encounter one another more frequently, both by chance and through local institutions, and to develop ties that are more likely to endure than more costly-to-maintain distant ties. By facilitating repeated interactions and development of overlapping social and professional connections, local concentrations of people engaged in similar technical activities create an environment facilitating trust building and rapid and effective diffusion of ideas … Through these networks flows information about promising new technical developments and important unsolved puzzles that can stimulate innovation by facilitating novel combinations of ideas and technologies and identifying emerging market opportunities. … Technological proximity also matters. The cumulativeness of technological advances and specificity of knowledge bases to particular technical areas and market applications makes the value of potential spillovers greater within rather than across specialized technological applications. (Aharonson et al., 2007, p.92)
The physical and human geography of certain temperate latitudes creates conditions for platforms and infrastructures for supporting technological innovation along fruitful historical developmental paths (Coe et al., 2012). Technological innovation is a human response to resource endowments, and environmental, climate and socio-economic changes (Chhetri et al., 2012; see also Singer et al., 1961). In particular, technological change is a human process of learning and adaptation to take advantage of important territorial opportunities and to cope with consequential environmental threats. Singer et al. (1961, vol. 1, Map 1 and p.37) show interesting maps that confirm the origin of the lithic technology in temperate latitudes in the northern hemisphere; in fact, several anthropological studies place Mousterian and other Palaeolithic industries of Neanderthal man in the geographical zone north of the Tropic of Cancer (see O’Brien and Shennan, 2010). Figure 4 shows these invariant linkages between climate and patterns of technological innovation over time.
Invariant linkages from temperate climate and suitable physical geographic factors to technological and economic progress
Temperate climate has been vital for human activity to create adaptation and learning processes for the emergence of opportunities, discoveries and inventions, and for the diffusion of innovations (O’Brien and Shennan, 2010). Even in a globalizing world, economic and innovative activities are geographically localized in urban areas of temperate latitudes (Dicken, 2003, pp.69–76). Worldwide urbanization is important for sharing the costs of a whole range of services and creating a variety of infrastructural, economic and cultural facilities (Bettencourt et al., 2007; c.f. also Coccia and Rolfo, 2007, 2013; Coccia, 2009d). This study shows that broad geo-economic areas in temperate latitudes support innovative outputs through a process of cumulative and self-reinforcing development. Temperate climate is basic to the population agglomeration required for the activities that lead to profitable paths of technological innovation: a central activity of learning and adaptation by complex societies to take advantage of important opportunities and/or to cope with consequential environmental threats (Rodima-Taylor et al., 2012; Olwig, 2012).
In addition, some economies in temperate climates have generated innovations that have locked them into a technological pattern. This path-dependency persists until a new techno-economic paradigm induces disequilibrium in geo-economic systems and changes the distribution of economic and innovative activities. Temperate climate is a necessary, but not sufficient, condition for supporting technological innovations. Temperate climate has to be associated with other driving forces in order to support long-run patterns of technological innovation (Coccia, 2010b, 2014a, 2014b).
Concluding observations
Climate is a geographical factor of the natural environment and a condition inducing technological innovation. In particular, human and physical capital is affected by climate (Abler et al., 2000) and temperate latitudes provide stimuli for social, technological and economic change (Hayami and Ruttan, 1985; Rosenberg, 1992; Smithers and Blay-Palmer, 2001). The progress of complex societies in temperate areas has generated innovation to reduce the influence of the natural environment and dependence on scarce resources (Hayami and Ruttan, 1985).
The present study shows high technological outputs in the temperate zones of the globe. This may be a result of the fortunate congruence of geographical and socio-cultural factors since the Palaeolithic period (Martin and Sunley, 1998; O’Brien and Shennan, 2010; Di Giano and Racelis, 2012). In particular, the temperate latitudes have created better conditions for supporting the ability of populations to adapt by means of technological innovations. Rodima-Taylor et al. (2012, p.107) claim that: ‘Innovations are human adaptations to changing needs and socio-economic conditions, and are therefore embedded in social processes’. Moreover, climate also affects cultural traits of societies that, through a process of learning, react and self-adapt to natural environmental conditions and resource endowments (Chhetri et al., 2012). Cultural traits are transmitted across generations within social systems, in the very long run as a result of institutions which preserve social memory (Walker et al., 2006; Spolaore and Wacziarg, 2013). The social memory of institutions plays a vital role in transforming experience, knowledge and cultural traits of people into adaptive strategies and learning processes. By means of high technical capability and innovation, these permit response to adverse environmental consequences (O’Brien and Shennan, 2010; Di Giano and Racelis, 2012). Hence, the climate and other physical geographic factors spur technological pathways and support the fortune of certain places. The emergence of technological innovation is a consequence of current and/or expected environmental stimuli and/or problems in order to reduce geo-economic risks and/or exploit beneficial opportunities (Smithers and Blay-Palmer, 2001).
Overall, then, the theoretical framework, underpinned with the evidence presented here, explains the main characteristics of the relationship between technological innovation and climate.
- (1)
The present conceptual framework assigns a central role to climate, which is neglected by the dominant approaches to the origins of technological innovation.
- (2)
The framework explains the role of localized economies in temperate latitudes in supporting patterns of technological innovation.
- (3)
The cumulative nature of processes of localized technological development shows that patterns of innovation are influenced by temperate climate and the historical developmental path created by complex societies in specific places.
- (4)
These results may help policymakers find geographical locations suited to technological change.
Of course, this study is explorative and far from conclusive. The role of climate on technological innovation deserves further scientific analysis. Future research should focus on the complex interaction among climate, the emergence of complex societies, patterns of technological innovation and human development by adopting psychological, historical, sociological and anthropological approaches. The partial analysis of the present study, focusing on a basic and partial linkage, provides interesting findings, but as Wright (1997, p.1562) admits, ‘In the world of technological change, bounded rationality is the rule’.